Smart Growth Policies Force Urbanites to Conform with Planners’ Prejudices

Published July 16, 2014

Debates over smart growth—sometimes known as new urbanism, compact cities, or sustainable urban planning, but always meaning higher urban densities and a higher share of people in multifamily housing—boil down to factual questions. But smart-growth supporters keep trying to twist the arguments into ideological issues.

For example, in response to my Minneapolis Star Tribune article about future housing demand, Thomas Fisher, dean of the College of Design at the University of Minnesota, writes:

“O’Toole, like many conservatives, equates low-density development with personal freedom.”

No, I equate personal freedom with personal freedom. 

Fisher adds, “we [meaning government] should promote density where it makes sense and prohibit it where it doesn’t”—in other words, restrict personal freedom whenever planners’ ideas of what “makes sense” differ from the people’s ideas.

Appeal to Patriotism

Another writer making this ideological argument is Daily Caller contributor Matt Lewis, who says conservatives should endorse new urbanism. He contends conservatives want people to love their country, high-density neighborhoods are prettier than low-density suburbs, and people who don’t have pretty places to live will stop loving their country. 

Lewis adds, “Nobody I know is suggesting that big government—or the U.N.!–ought to mandate or impose these sorts of development policies.” He apparently doesn’t know many urban planners, and certainly none in Denver, Portland, San Francisco, Seattle, the Twin Cities, or other metropolitan areas where big government in the form of regional planning agencies (though not the U.N.) are doing just that. If new urbanism were simply a matter of personal choice, no one would criticize it. 

Facts, Not Ideology

The real issues are factual, not ideological.

Fact #1: Contrary to University of Utah planning professor Arthur Nelson, most people prefer low-density housing once they have transport that is faster than walking. While a few people prefer higher densities, the market will provide, given that there is demand. 

Fact #2: Contrary to Matt Lewis, American suburbanization did not result from a “post-World War II push for sprawl” coming from “the tax code, zoning, a federally financed highway system, and so on.” Suburbanization began before the Civil War, when steam trains could move people faster than walking speed. Most American families abandoned transit and bought cars long before the advent of interstate highways—which, by the way, more than paid for themselves with the gas taxes collected from the people who drove on them. Nor did the tax code promote sprawl: Australians build bigger houses with higher homeownership rates in suburbs just as dispersed as America’s without a mortgage interest deduction

Fact #3: Contrary to Thomas Fisher, low-density housing costs less, not more, than high-density. Without urban-growth boundaries or other artificial restraints, there is almost no urban area in America short of land for housing. Multifamily housing costs more to build, per square foot, than single-family, and compact development is expensive because the planners tend to locate it in areas with the highest land prices. The prices cited in my article—$375,000 for a 1,400-square-foot home in a New Urban neighborhood vs. $295,000 for a 2,400-square-foot home on a large suburban lot—are typical for many smart-growth cities.

Fact #4: The so-called costs of sprawl are nowhere near as high as the costs of density. Rutgers University’s Costs of Sprawl 2000 estimates urban services to low-density development cost about $11,000 more per house than services to high-density development. However, pro-density policies added $130,000 to home prices in 2006.

Fact #5: Contrary to University of Minnesota planning professor Richard Bolan, the best way to reduce externalities such as pollution and greenhouse gases is to treat the source, not try to change people’s lifestyles. For example, since 1970 pollution controls reduced total air pollution from cars by more than 80 percent, whereas efforts to entice people out of their cars and onto transit reduced pollution by 0 percent.

Fact #6: Contrary to Lewis, suburbs are not sterile, boring places. Suburbanites have a strong sense of community and are more likely to engage in community affairs than city dwellers.

Fact #7: Smart growth doesn’t work. It doesn’t reduce driving: After taking self-selection into account, University of California economics professor David Brownstotne determine that smart growth’s effects on driving are “too small to be useful.” It doesn’t save money or energy: Multi-family housing not only costs more, it uses more energy per square foot than single-family, while transit costs more and uses as much or more energy per passenger mile as driving. When planners say smart growth saves energy, what they mean is you’ll live in a smaller house and have less mobility.

Fact #8: If we end all subsidies and land-use regulation, I’ll happily accept whatever housing and transport outcomes result from expression of personal preferences. Too many planners want to control population densities and transport choices through prescriptive land-use regulation and subsidies to their preferred forms of transportation and housing.

These planners think only government can know what is right for other people. Even if you believe that, government failure is worse than market failure, resulting in subsidies to special-interest groups for projects producing negligible social or environmental benefits.

Randal O’Toole ([email protected]) is a Cato Institute senior fellow on urban growth, public land, and transportation issues. Reprinted with permission from the Cato at Liberty blog.